Raül Romeva i Rueda

REFLEXIONS PERISCÒPIQUES

Reforma Política Pesquera UE: és hora de ser valents! / Reforming the Common Fisheries Policy:Now is no time to be timid!

Avui la Comissària d’Afers Marins, Maria Damanaki, ha presentat l’esborrany del que considera que ha de ser la reforma de la Política Pesquera de la UE. Després de mesos de discutir-ne, ara tenim un text sobre el qual començar a treballar políticament al Parlament Europeu (així com als estatals, nacionals i regionals). En tant que membre de la Comissió de Pesca del PE és, sens dubte, el debat més important i determinant que viurem els propers mesos, fins el gener de 2013 (que és quan se suposa que hem de tenir ja un acord final).

De moment, adjunto una nota de premsa de reacció a la proposta de la Comissària i un petit document en què resumeixo algunes de propostes que com a grup Verds/ALE entenem que cal tenir en compte, i que marquen les línees vermelles del que serà la nostra postura en les discussions i negociacions imminents, tot plegat amb una idea troncal: ara no és el moment de ser tímids en la reforma, ans al contrari, toca ser valents i afrontar amb visió de futur i responsabilitat canvis estructurals de fons en els diversos fronts que afecten l’activitat pesquera (captura, cria, engreix, mercat, consum, etiquetatge, …).

NOTA DE PRENSA – Bruselas, 13 de julio 2011

 

Reforma de la Política Pesquera Común

La Comisión presenta una tímida propuesta que no resuelve los retos de la política pesquera de la Unión Europea.

Luego de una larga espera, la Comisión Europea ha presentado hoy una propuesta de reforma de la Política Pesquera Común. Desde Verdes/ALE creemos que la comunicación no aborda correctamente los desafíos que suponen la pesquería en la UE, fracasa notablemente al intentar implementar un mecanismo de mercado de derechos de propiedad de pesca, tratándolos como bienes privados en lugar de considerarlos un bien común. Es decir, que no garantiza el objetivo global de sostenibilidad medioambiental.

Comentando sobre la propuesta de creación de derechos de propiedad, el Vicepresidente del grupo Verdes/ALE y Eurodiputado de ICV, Raül Romeva i Rueda, remarcó:

Sin una población sana y abundante de peces, nunca habrá una industria pesquera fuerte ni comunidades pesqueras.  La mayor prioridad de cualquier política de pesca  debe ser la sostenibilidad ambiental, con instrumentos que persigan y consigan garantizar unas pesquerías sanas y sostenibles; ésta es  una condición necesaria para el desarrollo económico y social sostenible de todas las actividades relacionadas con la pesca. La Comisión Europea fracasa al continuar adoptando un enfoque que enfrenta los objetivos de trabajo y de protección de las comunidades pesqueras con la conservación de las pesquerías. Éste es un error fundamental.

La propuesta de la Comisión de establecer un mecanismo de mercado para determinar quién tiene el derecho de pesca es un gran escándalo. Otorgar derechos de pesca comerciables provocará una mayor especulación y la concentración de los derechos de pesca en las manos de quienes más pueden pagar. Todavía peor, si los permisos de pesca son distribuidos en función de  la participación histórica en la actividad pesquera, el sistema permitirá a aquellos que fueron responsables de la sobreexplotación en el pasado, continuar siéndolo en el futuro.

Las pesquerías no son un bien privado cualquiera; todo lo contrario, son un recurso natural renovable que forma parte de nuestros bienes comunes. Las personas involucradas en actividades de pesca deben demostrar que sus actividades no dañan el medio marino y que generan contribuciones significativas a las comunidades costeras, para así garantizar el verdadero derecho a pescar.

El actual sistema de descartes es totalmente ineficiente y necesitamos ponerle fin. Celebramos que a Comisión haya reconocido este hecho, pero su enfoque tímido es claramente insuficiente.  La propuesta prohíbe solo los descartes de determinadas especies de peces que son explotadas comercialmente y fracasa al intentar establecer una conexión entre la prohibición y la necesidad de mejorar las técnicas de pesca y de selección para asegurar que los peces que no se pretende pescar no sean capturados en un primer momento.

Now is no time to be timid!

Reforming the Common Fisheries Policy

 

After thirty years of the Common Fisheries Policy (CFP), fisheries in the EU are in crisis, with depleted stocks, the industry lurching from crisis to disaster and back, and the continued long-term decline of coastal communities. These trends were evident before the CFP was created in 1982 but the Policy has notably failed to redress the situation.

Today, the Commission has unveiled its proposals to reform the CFP. They include some good elements but also some dangerous ones.

 

The Objectives of the CFP

A good, effective policy needs clear, coherent, concise objectives. No policy can be successful if what it is supposed to achieve is not clear and understood by those who are to implement it. However, the CFP has never had that luxury.

The formal objective is to provide “sustainable economic, environmental and social conditions”.  To that are added a variety of other objectives, including the precautionary approach and such matters as the interests of consumers and the standard of living of those in the sector. Yet there is no prioritization among these sometimes contradictory aims.

It is claimed that the Treaties do not allow a prioritization among environmental, economic and social sustainability. What such a legalistic argument ignores is that without abundant fish stocks, there can be no fishing industry and no fishing communities. Nonetheless, Ministers have consistently chosen to prioritize short term economic objectives over the conservation of resources. The failure of the CFP to conserve either fish or jobs is thus no surprise.

The Commission’s proposal does not resolve this problem, in fact it adds more objectives, making it even more confusing.

The Greens believe that the revised CFP must specifically set environmental sustainability, based on the precautionary approach and an ecosystem approach, as a fundamental prerequisite for economic and social sustainability.

 

How Much Fish can be Safely Caught?

Ministers have routinely ignored scientific advice and set fishing quotas higher than the fish stocks could sustain, in the name of protecting jobs. The result of this approach has been depleted fish stocks and an industry struggling to survive. In recent years some progress has been made in curbing this habit by the use of management plans. For certain fish stocks, these plans establish the quotas directly, based on the status of the stock. Ministers have tended to respect these plans and consequently, some of those stocks are recovering.

The Commission is seeking to strengthen these plans in a number of ways and that must be welcomed. Fisheries is an inexact science, full of uncertainties, and the proposal recognizes that. The plans are to allow stocks to recover to levels above those capable of producing “maximum sustainable yield” (MSY), while taking into account all of the uncertainties (unreliable catch data, limited biological information, etc.) which is an important step in the right direction. Unfortunately, the proposal sets no deadline for adopting management plans.

The Greens want to be more concise and more ambitious in setting targets. Fish stocks should be maintained at levels sufficiently above those capable of producing MSY (Maximum Sustainable Yield) so that they can fulfil their role in the marine ecosystem as predators or prey, while capable of supporting higher catches and so that fisheries can be profitable without continued subsidies. Plans should be adopted to that end for all regulated species by 2015.

 

What about Discards?

The current situation, where vast quantities of fish and other species (birds, turtles, marine mammals, etc) are caught and thrown away, dead, is a scandal and people are quite rightly angry about it. The reason that so much is thrown away is that fishermen have been less interested in improving the selectivity of their fishing than in increasing the amount they catch.

The Commission is proposing to ban the discarding of certain (but not all) commercially exploited fish species. The fishermen will have to bring them back to shore. The fish will still be dead, so the reason for the partial discard ban is to encourage the fishermen to avoid catching them in the first place, since bringing them ashore will have an economic impact. Unfortunately, the proposal does not establish a specific link between the partial discard ban and improvements in fishing techniques to improve selectivity.

 

Who Should Have the Right to Fish?

This is one of the most important questions in fisheries.

The Commission is proposing to allow the market to determine who can fish, by obliging the Member States to set up a system of fishing rights (such as quotas) that can be traded or sold, which could even lead to financial speculation on quotas. Experience shows that such a system all too often leads to concentration of the right to fish in the hands of those with the deepest pockets, since they can afford to pay the highest prices.

If fishing permits are granted based on historical participation in the fishery, with those who have had larger catches receiving the largest share of the quota, this will simply allow those who have been responsible for over-fishing in the past to continue fishing in the future.

This is doubtless the most controversial part of the Commission’s proposal.

But fish stocks are not commodities, they are natural, renewable common/public resources and the right to exploit them should be conditional upon fishing in an environmentally and socially responsible manner. Those involved in fishing activities should be required to demonstrate that their activities do not damage the marine environment and that they make significant contributions to coastal fishing communities. Member States should use such criteria when they allocate the right to fish, a possibility which exists in the proposal.

 

The Fishing Fleets

That the EU’s fishing fleets are too large and powerful for the fish that are available to be caught is not much disputed, even if most fishermen think that it is the fleets of other fishermen that should be reduced. Much of the excess fishing capacity is due to generous subsidies over a period of decades. It is the most serious problem that the CFP must deal with for it leads to irresistible political pressure to set quotas too high and therefore unsustainable and/or illegal fishing.

Twenty years of programmes aiming to reduce this capacity have largely failed. The Commission, in its proposal, is abandoning its earlier approach of attempting to regulate the fishing fleets by requiring reductions in fleet size. Rather, it makes the simple assumption that market forces, via the tradeable fishing rights, will accomplish the necessary reductions of the fleets. The market is supposed to reduce them to the appropriate size, but nothing is provided to ensure that only the appropriate types of fishing vessels remain.

Instead, fleet reductions need to be planned and regulated, in accordance with analyses on what resources are available to be caught, with the first steps being the elimination of the most environmentally destructive fishing vessels and gears.

 

Regionalization of the CFP

One of the major goals of the reform has always been to establish a policy that is less centralized, less dependent on detailed decisions taken in Brussels, so as to allow more opportunity for local and regional involvement in fisheries management. Such a shift in decision-making would need extremely clear language on who is responsible for what – the Council and the parliament, the Member States, or more local bodies The Commission’s proposal as written does not provide such clarity.

 

The External Dimension of the CFP

The EU fleets operate worldwide with 28% of the fish caught by European fishing boats taken outside EU waters (20% in international waters, and 8% under agreements with non-EU countries. The EU is also the world’s largest importer of fish products (over 60% of fish consumed in the EU). The EU has a special obligation to establish and respect high standards in the international arena.

The Commission has, for the first time, included provisions in the basic regulation concerning the external dimension of the CFP. What is proposed is positive as far as it goes, specifying what the EU should be aiming for in its bilateral fisheries agreements – abundant fish stocks, promotion of good governance in other countries. However, it provides no means of ensuring that EU vessels operating in waters of countries with no EU bilateral agreement shall meet the same standards.

 

Conclusions

The CFP has been blamed for many problems, but it must be remembered that it results from a political compromise by Ministers. Full and proper implementation of the current CFP would have prevented much of the current crisis faced by both fish and the fishing sector. Member States have signally failed in the past to implement what they have agreed. This reform, and its implementation, will show whether they truly wish to have a sustainable fishery in Europe or whether they want to continue the downward spiral.

 

Foto: La Comissària Damanaki durant la roda de premsa a la Comissió. Font: Romeva (via iPhone)



Deixa un comentari

L'adreça electrònica no es publicarà. Els camps necessaris estan marcats amb *

Aquest lloc està protegit per reCAPTCHA i s’apliquen la política de privadesa i les condicions del servei de Google.

Aquesta entrada s'ha publicat dins de Mars i oceans (pesca, tonyina, controls, Estratègia marina,...) per raulromeva | Deixa un comentari. Afegeix a les adreces d'interès l'enllaç permanent